This notebook is a slight modification of the one found in QuantEcon: The Solow-Swan Growth Model.
In this lecture we review a famous model due to Robert Solow (1925–2023) and Trevor Swan (1918–1989).
The model is used to study growth over the long run.
Although the model is simple, it contains some interesting lessons.
We will use the following imports.
import matplotlib.pyplot as plt
import numpy as np
The model¶
In a Solow–Swan economy, agents save a fixed fraction of their current incomes.
Savings sustain or increase the stock of capital.
Capital is combined with labor to produce output, which in turn is paid out to workers and owners of capital.
To keep things simple, we ignore population and productivity growth.
For each integer , output in period is given by , where is capital, is labor and is an aggregate production function.
The function is assumed to be nonnegative and homogeneous of degree one, meaning that
Production functions with this property include
- the Cobb-Douglas function with .
- the CES function with .
Here, is the output elasticity of capital and is a parameter that determines the elasticity of substitution between capital and labor.
We assume a closed economy, so aggregate domestic investment equals aggregate domestic saving.
The saving rate is a constant satisfying , so that aggregate investment and saving both equal .
Capital depreciates: without replenishing through investment, one unit of capital today becomes units tomorrow.
Thus,
Without population growth, equals some constant .
Setting and using homogeneity of degree one now yields
With , the final expression for capital dynamics is
Our aim is to learn about the evolution of over time, given an exogenous initial capital stock .
A graphical perspective¶
To understand the dynamics of the sequence we use a 45-degree diagram.
To do so, we first need to specify the functional form for and assign values to the parameters.
We choose the Cobb–Douglas specification and set , , and .
The function from (24.1) is then plotted, along with the 45-degree line.
Let’s define the constants.
A, s, alpha, delta = 2, 0.3, 0.3, 0.4
Now, we define the function .
def g(A, s, alpha, delta, k):
return A * s * k**alpha + (1 - delta) * k
Let’s plot the 45-degree diagram of .
def plot45(A, s, alpha, delta):
kstar = ((s * A) / delta) ** (1 / (1 - alpha))
x_max = int(kstar) + 2
xgrid = np.linspace(0, x_max, 12000)
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=(7, 5))
ax.set_xlim(0, x_max)
g_values = g(A, s, alpha, delta, xgrid)
ymin, ymax = np.min(g_values), np.max(g_values)
ax.set_ylim(ymin, ymax)
lb = r"$g(k) = sAk^{\alpha} + (1 - \delta)k$"
ax.plot(xgrid, g_values, lw=2, alpha=0.6, label=lb)
ax.plot(xgrid, xgrid, "k-", lw=1, alpha=0.7, label=r"$45^{\circ}$")
fps = (kstar,)
ax.plot(fps, fps, "go", ms=10, alpha=0.6)
ax.annotate(
r"$k^* = (sA / \delta)^{(1/(1-\alpha))}$",
xy=(kstar, kstar),
xycoords="data",
xytext=(-40, -60),
textcoords="offset points",
fontsize=14,
arrowprops=dict(arrowstyle="->"),
)
# Format x-axis ticks
ax.xaxis.set_major_formatter(plt.FuncFormatter(lambda x, p: f"{x:.1f}"))
# Format y-axis ticks
ax.yaxis.set_major_formatter(plt.FuncFormatter(lambda y, p: f"{y:.1f}"))
ax.legend(loc="upper left", frameon=False, fontsize=12)
ax.set_xlabel("$k_t$", fontsize=12)
ax.set_ylabel("$k_{t+1}$", fontsize=12)
plt.show()
plot45(A, s, alpha, delta)
Suppose, at some , the value lies strictly above the 45-degree line.
Then we have and capital per worker rises.
If then capital per worker falls.
If , then we are at a steady state and remains constant.
(A steady state of the model is a fixed point of the mapping .)
From the shape of the function in the figure, we see that there is a unique steady state in .
It solves and hence is given by
If initial capital is below , then capital increases over time.
If initial capital is above this level, then the reverse is true.
Let’s plot the 45-degree diagram to show the in the plot.
From our graphical analysis, it appears that converges to , regardless of initial capital .
This is a form of global stability.
from ipywidgets import FloatSlider, IntSlider, interact
interact(
plot45,
A=IntSlider(A, min=0, max=10, step=1),
s=FloatSlider(s, min=0, max=1, step=0.01),
alpha=FloatSlider(alpha, min=0, max=1, step=0.01),
delta=FloatSlider(delta, min=0, max=1, step=0.01),
)
The next figure shows three time paths for capital, from three distinct initial conditions, under the parameterization listed above.
At this parameterization, .
Let’s define the constants and three distinct initial conditions
A, s, alpha, delta = 2, 0.3, 0.3, 0.4
x0 = np.array([0.25, 1.25, 3.25])
ts_length = 20
xmin, xmax = 0, ts_length
ymin, ymax = 0, 3.5
def simulate_ts(x0_values, ts_length):
k_star = (s * A / delta) ** (1 / (1 - alpha))
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=[11, 5])
ax.set_xlim(xmin, xmax)
ax.set_ylim(ymin, ymax)
ts = np.zeros(ts_length)
# simulate and plot time series
for x_init in x0_values:
ts[0] = x_init
for t in range(1, ts_length):
ts[t] = g(A, s, alpha, delta, ts[t - 1])
ax.plot(
np.arange(ts_length),
ts,
"-o",
ms=4,
alpha=0.6,
label=r"$k_0=%g$" % x_init,
)
ax.plot(
np.arange(ts_length),
np.full(ts_length, k_star),
alpha=0.6,
color="red",
label=r"$k^*$",
)
ax.legend(fontsize=10)
ax.set_xlabel(r"$t$", fontsize=14)
ax.set_ylabel(r"$k_t$", fontsize=14)
plt.show()
simulate_ts(x0, ts_length)
As expected, the time paths in the figure all converge to .
Exercises¶
Exercise 24.1¶
Plot per capita consumption at the steady state, as a function of the savings rate , where .
Use the Cobb–Douglas specification .
Set and
Also, find the approximate value of that maximizes the and show it in the plot.
Solution toExercise 24.1¶
Steady state consumption at savings rate is given by
A = 2.0
alpha = 0.3
delta = 0.5
s_grid = np.linspace(0, 1, 1000)
k_star = ((s_grid * A) / delta) ** (1 / (1 - alpha))
c_star = (1 - s_grid) * A * k_star**alpha
Let’s find the value of that maximizes using scipyminimize_scalar
finds the minimum value.
from scipy.optimize import minimize_scalar
def calc_c_star(s):
k = ((s * A) / delta) ** (1 / (1 - alpha))
return -(1 - s) * A * k**alpha
return_values = minimize_scalar(calc_c_star, bounds=(0, 1))
s_star_max = return_values.x
c_star_max = -return_values.fun
print(f"Function is maximized at s = {round(s_star_max, 4)}")
Function is maximized at s = 0.3
x_s_max = np.array([s_star_max, s_star_max])
y_s_max = np.array([0, c_star_max])
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=[11, 5])
fps = (c_star_max,)
# Highlight the maximum point with a marker
ax.plot((s_star_max,), (c_star_max,), "go", ms=8, alpha=0.6)
ax.annotate(
r"$s^*$",
xy=(s_star_max, c_star_max),
xycoords="data",
xytext=(20, -50),
textcoords="offset points",
fontsize=12,
arrowprops=dict(arrowstyle="->"),
)
ax.plot(s_grid, c_star, label=r"$c*(s)$")
ax.plot(x_s_max, y_s_max, alpha=0.5, ls="dotted")
ax.set_xlabel(r"$s$")
ax.set_ylabel(r"$c^*(s)$")
ax.legend()
plt.show()
One can also try to solve this mathematically by differentiating and solve for using sympy.
from sympy import Symbol, solve
s_symbol = Symbol("s", real=True)
k = ((s_symbol * A) / delta) ** (1 / (1 - alpha))
c = (1 - s_symbol) * A * k**alpha
Let’s differentiate and solve using sympy.solve
# Solve using sympy
s_star = solve(c.diff())[0]
print(f"s_star = {s_star}")
s_star = 0.300000000000000
Incidentally, the rate of savings which maximizes steady state level of per capita consumption is called the Golden Rule savings rate.
Exercise 24.2¶
Stochastic Productivity
To bring the Solow–Swan model closer to data, we need to think about handling random fluctuations in aggregate quantities.
Among other things, this will eliminate the unrealistic prediction that per-capita output converges to a constant .
We shift to discrete time for the following discussion.
One approach is to replace constant productivity with some stochastic sequence .
Dynamics are now
We suppose is Cobb–Douglas and is IID and lognormal.
Now the long run convergence obtained in the deterministic case breaks down, since the system is hit with new shocks at each point in time.
Consider and
Generate and plot the time series .
Solution toExercise 24.2¶
Let’s define the constants for lognormal distribution and initial values used for simulation
# Define the constants
sig = 0.2
mu = np.log(2) - sig**2 / 2
A = 2.0
s = 0.6
alpha = 0.3
delta = 0.5
x0 = [0.25, 3.25] # list of initial values used for simulation
Let’s define the function k_next to find the next value of
def lgnorm():
return np.exp(mu + sig * np.random.randn())
def k_next(s, alpha, delta, k):
return lgnorm() * s * k**alpha + (1 - delta) * k
def ts_plot(x_values, ts_length):
fig, ax = plt.subplots(figsize=[11, 5])
ts = np.zeros(ts_length)
# simulate and plot time series
for x_init in x_values:
ts[0] = x_init
for t in range(1, ts_length):
ts[t] = k_next(s, alpha, delta, ts[t - 1])
ax.plot(
np.arange(ts_length),
ts,
"-o",
ms=4,
alpha=0.6,
label=r"$k_0=%g$" % x_init,
)
ax.legend(loc="best", fontsize=10)
ax.set_xlabel(r"$t$", fontsize=12)
ax.set_ylabel(r"$k_t$", fontsize=12)
plt.show()
ts_plot(x0, 50)